Trade openness and environmental quality: A literature review

PhD student. PHAM THI THUY DIEM (Banking University Ho Chi Minh City, University of Economics Ho Chi Minh City; Asian Journal of Economic s and Banking) and Professor. Dr. NGUYEN TRONG HOAI (Vice President of University of Economics Ho Chi Minh City)

ABSTRACT: 

The environmental effect of trade liberalization has been one of the most crucial questions concerning trade policy over the last two decades. However, the theoretical literature on trade openness and the environment is largely inconclusive relating to the overall influence of international trade on the environmental quality including displacement hypothesis, pollution haven hypothesis, foreign direct investment, “race to bottom”, diffusion of technology, and globalization. Previous studies demonstrate that trade openness have both positive and negative influence on the environmental quality.

Keywords: Trade openness, international trade, environmental quality.

1. Introduction

Trade openness could be one of the most crucial factors explaining EKC. Trade increases in size of the economy leading to an increase in pollution, hence trade, ceteris paribus, is the principal cause of environmental degradation. However, Birdsall and Wheeler (1993), Jones and Manuelli (1995), and Lee and Roland-Holst (1997) suggested that environmental damage linked to trade is not caused by trade. However, international trade has the contradictory influences on environmental quality, both positive and negative affect. Due to the scale effect (through an increase of the size of economy originating from an increase of trade volume), environmental quality could decline, hence increases pollution. However, trade could enhance the environmental quality via technique effect and/or composition effect (i.e., as trade increases income leading to environmental regulation and supervision is tightened). The environmental pollution was caused by the production of pollution-intensive goods reduces in one nation while it increases in other nation though international trade. This composition effect is attributed to two related hypotheses: displacement hypothesis and pollution haven hypothesis are two hypotheses associated with the contribution of composition effect. Fundamentally, there is no difference between these two hypotheses regarding comparative advantage in free trade. Due to trade relates one economy with international communities; a poor economy could rely on foreign technology transfer via foreign direct investment (FDI), which may reduce environmental pollution.

2. Trade openness and environmental quality: Theory and empirical evidence

  • Displacement hypothesis

According to Arrow et al. (1995), Stern, Common, and Barbier (1996), Ekins (1997) and Rothman (1998), it is accepted that consumption and international trade are linked under the structural change in production. More specially, the changes in the structural change in production is not accompanied by equivalent structure change in consumption in developed countries, thus EKC states that the migration or displacement of dirty industries from developed countries to less developed countries. The pollution-intensive industries migrate to less developed countries with weaker regulations from developed countries with stringent environmental regulations under certain circumstances (Copeland & Taylor, 1995). Nevertheless, the commodity composition of free trade in manufactures reflects the energy consumption in a country or a region (Agras & Chapman, 1999). Energy consumption and exports of manufactured goods have a positive relationship in countries (Suri & Chapman, 1998). Rich economies tend to become net importers of pollution-intensive goods while poor economies are likely to be net exporters following Saint-Paul (1994). The extracted inverted-U curve could be the consequence of changes in international specialization. It implies that richer economies are concentrated in “clean” and service-intensive goods industries while poor countries are focused on “dirty” and material-intensive goods industries, without altering the consumption (Cole, Elliot, & Azhar, 2001; Jänicke, Binder, & Mönch, 1997; Stern et al., 1996). Environmental impacts are being displaced from one economy to another due to the composition effect, rather than reduced (Rothman, 1998). These findings are consistent with the displacement hypothesis. In addition, the displacement hypothesis anticipates that openness or trade liberalization may lead to more fast growth of pollution-intensive goods industries in poor countries as rich countries enforce stringent environmental regulation and supervision (Harrison, 1995; Rock, 1996; Tobey, 1990).

  • Pollution haven hypothesis

Trade liberalization can be beneficial for environment quality (Antweiler et al., 2001a; Liddle, 2001). Free trade raises real income in poor countries, thereby leading to increased demands in stricter environmental protection as higher income individuals desire for a cleaner environment. On the other hand, if heavy polluting countries move to countries with weaker environmental regulation and supervision, lower trade barriers may damage environment. This called the pollution haven hypothesis. The pollution haven hypothesis implies the possibility that multinational enterprises with highly polluting activities migrate to countries with weaker environmental standards. The pollution haven hypothesis suggests that weaken environmental standards as a source of comparative advantage, thus shifting trade patterns. The pollution haven hypothesis is fundamentally a theory that argues that rich countries with stringent regulation and supervision may lose the dirty industries while poor countries would get them all.

  • Foreign direct investment

If developing countries reduce their environmental standards below efficiency levels for attracting foreign direct investment, they would provide pollution havens for dirty industries. Most developing countries base on technology transfer via foreign direct investment as a main means of technology acquisition. Thus, enterprises will reduce pollution damage by efficient and clean energy technologies. However, the rapid recent growth of global eco-consciousness and linking between trade, investment and environmental issues have the potential for disruption in these capital flows.

  • Race to bottom

The “race to bottom” scenario refers to relatively strict environmental standards in developed countries impose significant costs on polluters. Thus, polluting activities in developed economies suffer higher regulatory and supervision costs than their counterparts in less developed economies following Jaffe, Peterson, Portney, and Stavins (1995) and Mani and Wheeler (1998). This creates a strong incentive for some seriously polluting industries to displace and thereby the reallocation of international capital takes place. The rise of capital outflows may force developed country governments to relax environmental standards. As the ensuing race to bottom accelerates, the EKC flattens and rises toward highest existing level of pollution (Dasgupta, Laplante, Wang, & Wheeler, 2002).

  • Diffusion of technology

With free trade, technological innovation becomes more important than in the closed market economy. Thus, developed economies must continually innovate not only to maintain their economic growth but even to keep their real incomes. Economic latecomers from requiring the same levels of energy and materials inputs per unit of gross domestic product are prevented by diffusion of technology, rather than older industrialized countries needed in past. Free trade enhances clean technology diffusion (Reppelin-Hill, 1999; Wheeler & Martin, 1992). Some studies have argued that this might allow less developed economies to dive through the EKC (Magnani, 2000).

  • Globalization

According to Wheeler (2001), globalization may trigger the environmental race to bottom by an increase in competition for investment and jobs. Actually, “the bottom” rises with economic growth. Less developed countries enhance their environmental quality and standard as investment increases employment and income. Thus, globalization has been generally compatible with pollution reduction (Dessus & Bussolo, 1998; Grether & De Melo, 2003; Robison, 1988). Driving force of global economic growth is economic globalization; however, the benefits of this process is controversial (Tisdell, 2001). Globalization, liberalization and economic openness raise the issue of potential conflicts in two powerful current trends: the market-oriented economic reform process now extensively accepted worldwide, and environmental protection.

Table 1 shows a systematic review of empirical evidence on impact of trade openness on environment. The environmental effects of trade openness has received considerably much attention in the last two decades. However, the empirical evidence for the link between openness and environment quality is controversy and inconsistent in general (Antweiler et al., 2001a; Baek et al., 2009; Cole and Elliott, 2003; Frankel and Rose, 2005; Kearsley and Riddel, 2010).

Table 1. Openness and environmental quality

openness_and_environmental_quality

2_openness_and_environmental_quality

Notes: TradeOpen – Trade openness; EQ – environmental quality; (+) positive effects; (−) negative effects ; FE - Fixed effect estimator; RE - Random effects estimator; CVAR - The cointegrated vector autoregression; ARDL - Auto regressive distributed lag; JCM - Johansen  cointegration method; OLS - Ordinary least squares; VECM - Vector Error Correction Method ; VAR - The vector autoregressive; IV - Instrumental variables techniques; GLS - Feasible generalized least squares estimation; VECM - The vector error correction model; GIRF - Generalized impulse-response functions; GMM - The generalized methods of moments estimator.

3. Conclusions

There are several aspects differ from Antweiler, Copeland, and Taylor (2001a); therefore, future works aim at filling these research gaps. Firstly, research on the impact of trade openness on environmental quality under considering financial openness has received less attention, especially for developing economies. Hence, this paper aims to close the aforementioned gap in the literature, by examining whether and how environmental quality is influenced by trade openness in developing economies. Secondly, one of the major research gaps is the adoption of the regression model based on the Bayesian model averaging proposed by Fernandez, Ley, and Steel (2001b) to take into account model uncertainty in this relationship. Thirdly, this paper provides a systematic review of relevant empirical studies that has not been documented before. Fourthly, energy consumption is considered as a major cause of greenhouse gases emissions, which influence environmental quality through a variety of unfavorable ways. Hence, the inclusion of energy consumption as a key determinant of environmental quality. Last but not least, there is a persistent scarcity of empirical studies on the impacts of trade openness on environmental quality for developing economies using legal origins variable as a key determinant of CO2 emissions via the shaping of governance mechanisms, leading to overall institutional logics that govern human behavior.

 

REFERENCE:

  1. Agras, J., & Chapman, D. (1999). A dynamic approach to the Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis. Ecological Economics, 28(2), 267-277.
  2. Ang, J. B. (2009). CO2 emissions, research and technology transfer in China. Ecological Economics, 68(10), 2658-2665.
  3. Antweiler, W., Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2001a). Is free trade good for the environment? American Economic Review, 91(4), 877-908.
  4. Arrow, K., Bolin, B., Costanza, R., Dasgupta, P., Folke, C., Holling, C. S., . .. Perrings, C. (1995). Economic growth, carrying capacity, and the environment. Ecological Economics, 15(2), 91-95.
  5. Atici, C. (2009). Carbon emissions in Central and Eastern Europe: environmental Kuznets curve and implications for sustainable development. Sustainable Development, 17(3), 155-160.
  6. Atici, C. (2012). Carbon emissions, trade liberalization, and the Japan–ASEAN interaction: A group-wise examination. Journal of the Japanese International Economies, 26(1), 167-178.
  7. Baek, J., Cho, Y., & Koo, W. W. (2009). The environmental consequences of globalization: A country-specific time-series analysis. Ecological Economics, 68(8-9), 2255-2264.
  8. Birdsall, N., & Wheeler, D. (1993). Trade policy and industrial pollution in Latin America: where are the pollution havens? The Journal of Environment Development, 2(1), 137-149.
  9. Chebbi, H. E., Olarreaga, M., & Zitouna, H. (2011). Trade openness and CO 2 emissions in Tunisia. Middle East Development Journal, 3(01), 29-53.
  10. Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics, 81(1), 163-192.
  11. Choi, E., Heshmati, A., & Cho, Y. (2010). An empirical study of the relationships between CO2 emissions, economic growth and openness. Retrieved from https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1708750.
  12. Cole, M. A., & Elliott, R. (2003). Determining the trade–environment composition effect: the role of capital, labor and environmental regulations. Journal of Environmental Economics Management, 46(3), 363-383.
  13. Cole, M. A., Elliot, R. J., & Azhar, A. K. (2001). The determinants of trade in pollution intensive industries: North-South evidence. University of Birmingham.
  14. Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (1995). Trade and the environment: a partial synthesis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 77(3), 765-771.
  15. Dasgupta, S., Laplante, B., Wang, H., & Wheeler, D. (2002). Confronting the environmental Kuznets curve. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(1), 147-168.
  16. Dessus, S., & Bussolo, M. (1998). Is there a trade-off between trade liberalization and pollution abatement?: a computable general equilibrium assessment applied to Costa Rica. Journal of Policy Modeling, 20(1), 11-31.
  17. Ekins, P. (1997). The Kuznets curve for the environment and economic growth: examining the evidence. Environment and Planning A, 29(5), 805-830.
  18. Frankel, J. A. (2009). Environmental effects of international trade. Faculty Research Working Paper Series.
  19. Frankel, J. A., & Rose, A. K. (2005). Is trade good or bad for the environment? Sorting out the causality. Review of Economics Statistics, 87(1), 85-91.
  20. Grether, J. M., & De Melo, J. (2003). Globalization and dirty industries: Do pollution havens matter?(No. w9776). National Bureau of Economic Research. (nước nào?)
  21. Harrison, A. (1995). Openness and growth: A time-series, cross-country analysis for developing countries. Journal of development Economics48(2), 419-447.
  22. Jaffe, A. B., Peterson, S. R., Portney, P. R., & Stavins, R. N. (1995). Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of US manufacturing: what does the evidence tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 33(1), 132-163.
  23. Jalil, A., & Mahmud, S. F. (2009). Environment Kuznets curve for CO2 emissions: a cointegration analysis for China. Energy policy, 37(12), 5167-5172.
  24. Jänicke, M., Binder, M., & Mönch, H. (1997). ‘Dirty industries’: patterns of change in industrial countries. Environmental Resource Economics, 9(4), 467-491.
  25. Jones, L. E., & Manuelli, R. E. (1995). A positive model of growth and pollution controls(No. w5205). National Bureau of Economic Research.
  26. Kearsley, A., & Riddel, M. (2010). A further inquiry into the Pollution Haven Hypothesis and the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Ecological Economics, 69(4), 905-919.
  27. Kose, M. A., Prasad, E., Rogoff, K., & Wei, S. J. (2009). Financial globalization: a reappraisal. IMF Staff papers56(1), 8-62.
  28. Le, T. H., Chang, Y., & Park, D. (2016). Trade openness and environmental quality: International evidence. Energy policy, 92, 45-55.
  29. Lee, H., & Roland-Holst, D. (1997). The environment and welfare implications of trade and tax policy. Journal of Development Economics, 52(1), 65-82.
  30. Levine, R. (2001). International financial liberalization and economic growth. Review of International Economics, 9(4), 688-702.
  31. Liddle, B. (2001). Free trade and the environment-development system. Ecological Economics, 39(1), 21-36.
  32. Magnani, E. (2000). The Environmental Kuznets Curve, environmental protection policy and income distribution. Ecological Economics, 32(3), 431-443.
  33. Managi, S. (2004). Trade liberalization and the environment: carbon dioxide for 1960-1999. Economics Bulletin, 17(1), 1-5.
  34. Managi, S., Hibiki, A., & Tsurumi, T. (2008). Does Trade Liberalization Reduce Pollution Emissions? Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/eti/dpaper/08013.html.
  35. Managi, S., Hibiki, A., & Tsurumi, T. (2009). Does trade openness improve environmental quality? Journal of Environmental Economics Management, 58(3), 346-363.
  36. Mani, M., & Wheeler, D. (1998). In search of pollution havens? Dirty industry in the world economy, 1960 to 1995. The Journal of Environment Development, 7(3), 215-247.
  37. McKinnon, R. I. (1973). Money and capital in economic development: Brookings Institution Press.
  38. Mishkin, F. S. (2009). Why we shouldn't turn our backs on financial globalization. IMF Staff papers, 56(1), 139-170.
  39. Mutascu, M. (2018). A time-frequency analysis of trade openness and CO2 emissions in France. Energy policy115, 443-455.
  40. Nasir, M., & Rehman, F. U. (2011). Environmental Kuznets curve for carbon emissions in Pakistan: an empirical investigation. Energy policy, 39(3), 1857-1864.
  41. Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (2003). The great reversals: the politics of financial development in the twentieth century. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(1), 5-50.
  42. Reppelin-Hill, V. (1999). Trade and environment: An empirical analysis of the technology effect in the steel industry. Journal of Environmental Economics Management, 38(3), 283-301.
  43. Robison, H. D. (1988). Industrial pollution abatement: the impact on balance of trade. Canadian Journal of Economics, 187-199.
  44. Rock, M. T. (1996). Pollution intensity of GDP and trade policy: can the World Bank be wrong? World development, 24(3), 471-479.
  45. Rothman, D. S. (1998). Environmental Kuznets curves—real progress or passing the buck?: A case for consumption-based approaches. Ecological Economics, 25(2), 177-194.
  46. Saint-Paul, G. (1994). The Economics of Sustainable Development. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press.
  47. Shahbaz, M., Nasreen, S., Ahmed, K., & Hammoudeh, S. (2016). Trade openness–carbon emissions nexus: the importance of turning points of trade openness for country panels. Energy Economics, 61, 221-232.
  48. Stern, D. I., Common, M. S., & Barbier, E. B. (1996). Economic growth and environmental degradation: The environmental Kuznets curve and sustainable development. World development, 24(7), 1151-1160. doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(96)00032-0.
  49. Suri, V., & Chapman, D. (1998). Economic growth, trade and energy: implications for the environmental Kuznets curve. Ecological Economics, 25(2), 195-208.
  50. Svaleryd, H., & Vlachos, J. (2002). Markets for risk and openness to trade: how are they related? Journal of International Economics, 57(2), 369-395.
  51. Tisdell, C. (2001). Globalisation and sustainability: environmental Kuznets curve and the WTO. Ecological Economics, 39(2), 185-196.
  52. Tobey, J. A. (1990). The effects of domestic environmental policies on patterns of world trade: an empirical test. Kyklos, 43(2), 191-209.
  53. Wheeler, D. (2001). Racing to the bottom? Foreign investment and air pollution in developing countries. The Journal of Environment Development, 10(3), 225-245.
  54. Wheeler, D., & Martin, P. (1992). Prices, policies, and the international diffusion of clean technology: The case of wood pulp production. International trade and the environment. - Washington, DC, 197-224.

 

ĐỘ MỞ THƯƠNG MẠI VÀ CHẤT LƯỢNG MÔI TRƯỜNG:

TỔNG QUAN LÝ THUYẾT

NCS. PHẠM THỊ THÚY DIỄM

Trường Đại học Ngân hàng Thành phố Hồ Chí Minh

Tạp chí Kinh tế và Ngân hàng châu Á

GS. TS. NGUYỄN TRỌNG HOÀI

Phó Hiệu trưởng Trường Đại học Kinh tế Thành phố Hồ Chí Minh

TÓM TẮT:

Tác động môi trường của tự do hóa thương mại là một trong những câu hỏi quan trọng trong chính sách thương mại hơn 2 thập kỷ gần đây. Tuy nhiên, tổng quan lý thuyết về độ mở thương mại và môi trường vẫn chưa thống nhất liên quan đến ảnh hưởng tổng thể của thương mại quốc tế lên chất lượng môi trường, bao gồm: giả thuyết chuyển dời, giả thuyết nơi ẩn giấu ô nhiễm, đầu tư trực tiếp nước ngoài, “cuộc đua xuống đáy”, khuyến tán công nghệ và toàn cầu hóa. Các nghiên cứu trước cho thấy rằng, độ mở thương mại có cả tác động tích cực lẫn tiêu cực lên chất lượng môi trường.

Từ khóa: Độ mở thương mại, thương mại quốc tế, chất lượng môi trường.